This group brings together the best thinkers on energy and climate. Join us for smart, insightful posts and conversations about where the energy industry is and where it is going.

Post

Why a Climate Treaty or Carbon Tax Is Unlikely

Steven Cohen's picture
The Earth Institute, Columbia University
  • Member since 2018
  • 101 items added with 58,460 views
  • Apr 22, 2014
  • 697 views

Climate Treaty and Carbon Tax

The climate crisis is real and it requires an immediate and continuous response, but it is very unlikely that the response will be a treaty or a tax. For a long time I have been observing colleagues arguing that we must limit greenhouse gas emissions via a binding international treaty. Often the same colleagues will say that we need to limit emissions by pricing carbon to discourage its use. As economists are prone to say: all things held equal; that solution should work. Sadly, few things are held equal and so these two policy “solutions” are actually distractions, since they are both politically infeasible.

Let’s start with the treaty idea. Kyoto in December 1997 was the high point of the treaty strategy, as nations agreed to reduce emissions. When the U.S. refused to go along, the international agreement began to unravel. Even though the treaty “went into effect in 2005,” it’s never been a meaningful policy. If the U.S. had ratified the agreement, it still wouldn’t have mattered, since the treaty would never have been implemented anyway. Developing nations need energy to develop and developed nations continue to find more uses for energy than ever before. The resulting political pressure to develop and use energy is so strong that limits on greenhouse gasses are routinely ignored. In developed nations, improved energy efficiency and increased use of renewable energy are reducing greenhouse gas emissions, but in the developing world, emissions are growing at a furious rate.

Energy is simply too central to economic life, and economic life too central to the political elite’s power, to allow anyone to limit a nation’s use of energy. That is why the likelihood of a climate treaty is so low. Climate change has low political salience because its causes are everywhere and its main impact is either in the future or difficult to predict.

This brings me to the carbon tax. What a simple and elegant solution. Simply price fossil fuels at their true cost, including their impact on the environment and the costs of damage from climate-induced extreme weather. The problem, again, is the importance of energy. Increased energy costs would have an impact on the price of everything. One could argue that it would force efficiency and push renewables into the marketplace and that the cost impact would be temporary; but economic life involves psychology and confidence, and the temporary negative could set in motion other negatives as well. Now couple the short-term negative economic impact of a carbon tax with America’s political allergy to most forms of taxation. Which politician is going to campaign on that platform? It is true that you could design a tax that provides rebates to poor people and addresses other negative impacts, but don’t waste your time–the probability of an American carbon tax is very, very low.

Well-respected scholars continue to make the case for carbon taxes, international treaties and nuclear power, oblivious to the political obstacles of each of those policy paths. A treaty cannot overcome the distinct and conflicting political perspectives caused by different rates of economic development. A tax cannot overcome America’s antipathy to new taxes. Nuclear power cannot overcome “not in my backyard” objections to siting generation or waste facilities.

The late, great speaker of the U.S. House of Representatives Tip O’Neill famously argued that “all politics is local.” In political science 101 we teach Harold Lasswell’s eighty-year-old definition of politics as the process that determines “who gets what, when and how”. Politics is about distributing and receiving benefits and costs. Robert Dahl added to Lasswell’s definition by speaking of politics involving the “authoritative allocation” of benefits and costs. Combining Lasswell and Dahl, what do we get? We learn that economic power, tangible local impacts, physical force and legitimate legal authority matter. Policy is not a puzzle to be solved objectively, but a direction that must be adjusted to the currents of substantive and even symbolic notions of self-interest. There are too many interests aligned against the treaty and the tax for those policies to make it safely through the white water rapids of climate politics. We need to look for policies that do not have as many entrenched natural enemies. We need to find and cultivate friends instead of making and fighting enemies.

There are countless examples of policy adjustments to political interest. Here’s a new and old example of what I mean:

  1. Obamacare: The reason why the Affordable Care Act looks the way it does was because the economic power of health insurance companies had to be accommodated. As single payer system might have been simpler and easier to administer, but it would have been killed by the insurance companies.
  2. Water Pollution Control: In 1972, when the Federal Water Pollution Control Act was passed over President Richard Nixon’s veto, he used his executive authority to impound funding for water management planning. However, due to the pressure of the construction unions, engineering companies and state and local elected leaders, he allocated billions of dollars to construct sewage treatment plants. Nixon was against regulating water pollution and against planning that would guide the siting of sewage treatment plants, but he still ended up supporting the funding of those plants. Sewage treatment plants were sometimes sited in the wrong place, but they still resulted in dramatic improvements in America’s water quality. Nixon may not have cared about water quality, but he understood the political benefits of pouring concrete.

Logic, rationality and elegant policy design typically take a back seat to bare knuckle, self-interested, and often local, politics. If we want to mitigate climate change, why not look at a policy design that offers hope instead of futility? Aren’t there any policy perspectives that can avoid the difficulties of these standard approaches? I think there are.

Let’s face the fact that our lifestyles and the aspirations of billions of people in the developing world will require more, not less, energy in the future. I think our policy goal should be to lower the price of energy and reduce the proportion of the GDP devoted to energy. We can do that by replacing fossil fuels, which will only get more expensive over time, with renewable energy, which has been getting less expensive over time. Most people who fill up their gas tank know that what used to cost $25 now costs $50. While there may be plenty of fossil fuel supplies left in the crust of the earth, it is increasingly complicated to get it out of the ground, transport it and burn it. Why don’t we focus our brainpower on developing cheaper, more reliable and more convenient forms of renewable energy? Let’s direct policy toward developing and implementing new renewable energy and energy storage technologies. Let’s build smart grids, decentralized energy generation capacity and new forms of energy storage capacity. Let’s turn our focus from reducing the use of dirty energy to increasing the use of clean energy. It’s not hard to imagine a political leader running on that platform. Is it?

Our goal should be to have the new technology of renewable energy drive out the old technology of fossil fuels. It’s been done before: tapes replaced records, CDs replaced tapes, and MP3s replaced CDs. Cars replaced horses and cellphones replaced landlines–and someday, the electric car will replace the internal combustion engine. Our policy focus should be on inventing new technologies through government-funded research and development and then commercializing those technologies through private enterprise. Government can help direct capital toward the commercialization of new technologies and can use its vast purchasing power to help speed the implementation of these new technologies. While some old line fossil fuel companies and energy utilities might resist, the new companies that will build these new technologies will provide a powerful counter weight to the political power of these declining businesses. It is also possible that the better run fossil fuel companies will become modern energy companies and move into the renewable energy business for real, not just in their green-washing commercials.

While a climate treaty or carbon tax is unlikely, addressing the climate crisis is inevitable. To do that, we need to avoid the distraction of unattainable policies and focus on policies that are politically feasible.

Photo Credit: Treaties and Taxes and Likelihood/shutterstock

Discussions
Ed Dodge's picture
Ed Dodge on Apr 22, 2014

How about a Production Tax Credit for CCUS-EOR?  There is already one on the books but it was poorly written and no one has been able to take advantage of it.

Sequestering CO2 via Enhanced Oil Recovery is one of the few proven methods we have available to pull millions, if not billions, of tons of CO2 away from the atmosphere and store it safely underground.  CCS is expensive when applied punitively to a coal power plant or when fashioned as a waste disposal exercise, but when applied to EOR CO2 is a valuable commodity with a large margin of demand from oil producers.

A production tax credit of roughly $20/ton for CO2 helps bridge the crucial financing gap between the cost of capturing carbon which ranges from $60-$90/ton and the price oil producers are willing to pay which is around $30/ton.  This tax proposal is revenue positive because the credits are made up for by taxing the oil production under existing laws.

The NEORI, National Enhanced Oil Recovery Initiative, has developed very detailed proposals for both correcting the existing tax credit and a new more comprehensive program.  CCUS-EOR has support from both the fossil fuel industries and leading green groups such as EDF and NRDC, a rarity these days and it does not require a grand bargain on taxes or climate.  Just a discreet piece of legislation that will enable the USA to build the infrastructure needed to capture, transport and utilize vast quantities of CO2 and keep it out of the atmosphere.

We cannot separate energy security from energy pollution.  Both issues need to be resolved in tandem. This initiative addresses both.

John Miller's picture
John Miller on Apr 22, 2014

If politicians were successful in negotiating and getting an International climate treaty, carbon tax or more effective energy policies approved by most Governments (including the U.S.), the likelihood of stabilizing and significantly reducing total world carbon emissions within our and our children’s lifetimes appears to be relatively small.  Even if the OECD (Developed) Countries achieved the goal of the original Kyoto Protocol (80% reduction of 1990 levels), the probability of non-OECD (Developing) Countries controlling, let alone reducing their carbon emissions, and stabilizing world total carbon emissions by mid-century is highly uncertain.  Refer to a past TEC Post, fourth graph (“Carbon Emissions Based on Reducing OECD Emission by 80% of 1990 Levels”).

The feasibility problem statement begins with China; the number one source of world carbon emissions since 2005 and growing.  Unless lower carbon energy sources truly become competitive with fossil fuels in overall World Free Markets, the ability of Developing Countries (with their continuously growing populations and directional standards’ of living improvements) to switch from currently more economic fossil fuels to higher cost renewables, will be extremely challenging.

Nathan Wilson's picture
Nathan Wilson on Apr 23, 2014

Nuclear power cannot overcome “not in my backyard” objections to siting generation or waste facilities. ‘

Nuclear power plants and waste repositories do not produce air pollution and have a very low visual impact due to their very small size for the energy they produce relative to renewables.  They also provide lots of high paying jobs, which are much safer than jobs in most other industries (and all other energy industries).

I therefore must conclude that the public aversion to nuclear power comes not from any features which are intrinsic to nuclear, but result from the fact that they represent an existential threat to the highly influencial fossil fuel competition (so the fossil fuel industry has lobbied to push public opinion away from nuclear).

Any fossil fuel alternative which grow large enough and have sufficient promise to threaten fossil fuels can expect to experience similar oppostion.


‘…by replacing fossil fuels, which will only get more expensive over time, with renewable energy, which has been getting less expensive over time.’

This is a dangerous delusion that appears to be widely shared by renewble enthusiasts.  Coal has been cheap, and continues to be cheap, with no resource depletion in sight.  Coal can easily scale up if the cost of natural gas or petroleum rises too much.  Coal is the primary energy source of developing nations.

Solar and wind costs have decreased greatly from their first-of-a-kind pricing, as would be expected.  But energy storage has not.  Unlike solar and wind, the battery industry is old and mature, with a very large cost gap that must be crossed to threaten even petroleum (the most costly of all fossil fuels).  

For this reason, we should expect that solar and wind will not advance to a penetration which is higher than the capacity factor (e.g. 30% and 15% for wind and solar respectively), with the remainder provided by flexible generation (i.e. fossil fuel), no matter how low their costs fall.  In contrast, nuclear can essentially replace coal plants on a  one-for-one basis.

Given that the per capita energy consumption in the developing world is far lower than in developed nations and clearly must rise substantially to eliminate global poverty, a partial solution (like solar and wind) which requires 50% of grid electricity to come from fossil fuels will simply not allow our CO2 emission to be low enough (without CC&S).

Bob Meinetz's picture
Bob Meinetz on Apr 23, 2014

Steven, you’ll have to make a trip to British Columbia and explain to its residents why their revenue-neutral carbon tax, which in its first six years has resulted in a 17% drop in gasoline use, a 6% reduction in carbon emissions, and the lowest income taxes in all of Canada – isn’t the unqualified success it appears to be. They’re operating under the delusion that it is, and I can’t say I blame them.

A similar tax in the U.S. could result in a carbon savings of 271 MtCO2e – the equivalent of taking 12.6 million cars off the road – without any adverse effect on the economy.

 

Robert Hargraves's picture
Robert Hargraves on Apr 23, 2014

I strongly agree with the premise that carbon taxes are unlikely. Even if wealthy countries such as the US could agree to them, the developing world so desparately needs affordable electricity they will burn what ever is cheapest — now coal. But you discount the possibility that advanced nuclear power can provide energy cheaper than coal, writing Nuclear power cannot overcome “not in my backyard” objections to siting generation or waste facilities. Objections are becoming overcome. Support for nuclear power is increasing. In Nevada two candidates for the US House or Representatives are supporting the Yucca Mountain waste depository. Politicians in Texas are rallying support for a waste isolation facility in West Texas. Just this week, China announced negotiations with Westinghouse for eight (8) more AP1000 reactors.

Thomas Garven's picture
Thomas Garven on Apr 23, 2014

A very well written piece.

It might be possible for us to make some progress if everyone just started thinking about what they can personally do to clean up the “air they breath and the water they drink”.  

Think about that for a minute – 300 million Americans looking for ways to improve things for themselves. If enough people did just this one thing everything else would probably just fall into place. 

Nathan Wilson's picture
Nathan Wilson on Apr 23, 2014

If enough people did just this one thing everything…”

That would be great if our CO2 emissions were too high by 10 or 20%.  But no, baby steps are not enough.  We need to slash emissions by 80% or so, all while doubling or tripling global energy use.

The only solution is change our primary energy source from fossil fuels to a mix of renewables and nuclear.  For example, we could replace all coal use with nuclear, replace most natural gas use with solar and electricity, and replace most petroleum use with batteries and/or carbon-free hydrogen and ammonia (made from renewable and nuclear energy or fossil fuel with CC&S).  These are very challenging actions which cannot be achieved using baby steps or any variation on business as ususal.

Engineer- Poet's picture
Engineer- Poet on Apr 24, 2014

I figure we’ll have real carbon sequestration when we have the excess energy to turn it into molten polyethylene and inject it into old oil and gas wells.  It’s one of the few things I can think of that would avoid any significant contamination and make quite sure that it wasn’t going to leak out again.

Thomas Garven's picture
Thomas Garven on Apr 24, 2014

Your plan also works Nathan and my vote goes to the High Termperature Gas Cooled Reactor [HTGR].  The reactors of the future [if we are going to have some] will produce more than just one product.  Like electricity and desalination or electricity and hydrogen. That is the only way I see nuclear becoming cost competitive in the near term.

Bob Meinetz's picture
Bob Meinetz on Apr 24, 2014

Robert, what do you believe is non-transferable about BC’s revenue-neutral carbon tax, essentially the same policy that has been advocated by climatologist James Hansen for years? It’s been proven effective, and is supported by 60% of BC residents.

Granted, this approach is not yet applicable to large swaths of rural China or Brazil. It is applicable in the areas of the world with the highest per-capita carbon emissions – the areas where it could have the greatest immediate effect.

Steven Cohen's picture
Thank Steven for the Post!
Energy Central contributors share their experience and insights for the benefit of other Members (like you). Please show them your appreciation by leaving a comment, 'liking' this post, or following this Member.
More posts from this member

Get Published - Build a Following

The Energy Central Power Industry Network® is based on one core idea - power industry professionals helping each other and advancing the industry by sharing and learning from each other.

If you have an experience or insight to share or have learned something from a conference or seminar, your peers and colleagues on Energy Central want to hear about it. It's also easy to share a link to an article you've liked or an industry resource that you think would be helpful.

                 Learn more about posting on Energy Central »